Liz Truss Is Not to Blame for the UK Market Turmoil

CommentaryWe live in strange times. The same people that vehemently defended massive deficit spending and money printing as the solution to the global economy now blame the turmoil of the UK bond and currency markets on a deficit-increasing budget. I find it astonishing that not one of the so-called experts who have immediately placed the cause of the British market volatility on Prime Minister Liz Truss’s budget have said anything about the collapse of the yen and the need for Bank of Japan intervention, which has been ongoing for two weeks. Why did so many people assume the Truss mini-budget was the cause of volatility when the euro, the yen, the Norwegian krone, and most emerging market currencies have suffered a similar or worse depreciation versus the U.S. dollar this year? What about the bond market? This is the worst year since 1931 for bonds all over the world, and the collapse in prices of sovereign and private bonds in developed and emerging market economies is strikingly similar to that of their UK fixed-income peers. The same economists that say deficits don’t matter and that sovereign nations can spend and print currency as they please (“expansionary policies,” they call them) now say that a UK Keynesian budget that increases spending, but cuts taxes, may destroy the economy. Yet they forget Japan had to massively intervene in the yen as well without any tax cuts and keeping its misguided fiscal policy of spending and borrowing. British pension funds aren’t selling sovereign bonds because of a lack of trust in this or another government’s budget. They’re selling negative-yielding sovereign bonds because they jumped wholeheartedly into the debt bubble created by artificially cheap money believing that central banks would keep fixed-income prices elevated with constant repurchases. British pension funds’ unfunded liabilities aren’t a problem caused by the mini-budget nor solely a UK problem. It was an enormous problem in 2019–2020 disguised by insane currency printing. Unfunded global liabilities for state pension funds in the United States were already $783 billion in 2021 and rose to $1.3 trillion in 2022, according to Reason Foundation. The funded ratio of state pensions was just 85 percent in 2021 and has fallen below 75 percent in 2022. What happened in the years of negative rates and massive currency printing? Pension funds used liability-driven investing (LDI) strategies. Most LDI mandates used derivatives to hedge inflation and interest rate risk. And what happens when inflation kicks in and rates rise? “As interest rates have risen, the notional value of some of the derivatives held in LDI portfolios has fallen. The result: increased collateral calls. The speed at which rates have risen means some pension plans have had to liquidate portfolios to meet collateral calls, according to the Investment Association’s latest report in September,” writes Brian Croce and colleagues at Pensions & Investment. The total assets in LDI strategies have almost quadrupled to 1.6 trillion pounds ($1.8 trillion) in the 10 years through 2021. “Nearly two-thirds of Britain’s defined benefit pension schemes use LDI funds, according to [The Pensions Regulator],” Reuters reported. Truss and her former Chancellor of the Exchequer Kwasi Kwarteng aren’t to blame for this insanity. The policy of negative real rates and massive liquidity injection by the Bank of England is. Kwarteng and Truss are only to blame for believing that the policies of spending and printing defended by almost all mainstream Keynesian economists should work even when the music stops. In these past years, British and developed nations’ governments didn’t pay any attention to fiscal imbalances because money was cheap and abundant. Deficits soared, spending was uncontrolled, and the problem was hidden in the balance sheet of central banks that, like the Bank of England, purchased more than 100 percent of net issuances of government debt. After years of printing money and increasing debt to new all-time highs, persistent high inflation appeared, and now central banks need to hike rates and reduce money supply growth just when fixed-income funds are loaded with toxic debt at negative nominal and real yields. And the rate hikes mean margin calls are more expensive and losses are unbearable. UK pension funds need to get rid of the liquid assets they own as margin calls rise. Inflation arrived after years of massive currency printing and debt monetization, and investment funds all over the world—but especially in the euro area, UK, and Japan—are seeing their portfolios melt down with massive nominal and real losses. When margin calls kick in, many need to sell their most liquid assets, Gilts in the UK, or government bonds elsewhere. Truss and Kwarteng aren’t to blame for the insanity of the past years or the previous chancellor Rishi Sunak’s ultra-Keynesian budgets. They’re only to blame for believing that another dose of Keynesian deficit

Liz Truss Is Not to Blame for the UK Market Turmoil

Commentary

We live in strange times. The same people that vehemently defended massive deficit spending and money printing as the solution to the global economy now blame the turmoil of the UK bond and currency markets on a deficit-increasing budget.

I find it astonishing that not one of the so-called experts who have immediately placed the cause of the British market volatility on Prime Minister Liz Truss’s budget have said anything about the collapse of the yen and the need for Bank of Japan intervention, which has been ongoing for two weeks. Why did so many people assume the Truss mini-budget was the cause of volatility when the euro, the yen, the Norwegian krone, and most emerging market currencies have suffered a similar or worse depreciation versus the U.S. dollar this year? What about the bond market? This is the worst year since 1931 for bonds all over the world, and the collapse in prices of sovereign and private bonds in developed and emerging market economies is strikingly similar to that of their UK fixed-income peers.

The same economists that say deficits don’t matter and that sovereign nations can spend and print currency as they please (“expansionary policies,” they call them) now say that a UK Keynesian budget that increases spending, but cuts taxes, may destroy the economy. Yet they forget Japan had to massively intervene in the yen as well without any tax cuts and keeping its misguided fiscal policy of spending and borrowing.

British pension funds aren’t selling sovereign bonds because of a lack of trust in this or another government’s budget. They’re selling negative-yielding sovereign bonds because they jumped wholeheartedly into the debt bubble created by artificially cheap money believing that central banks would keep fixed-income prices elevated with constant repurchases.

British pension funds’ unfunded liabilities aren’t a problem caused by the mini-budget nor solely a UK problem. It was an enormous problem in 2019–2020 disguised by insane currency printing. Unfunded global liabilities for state pension funds in the United States were already $783 billion in 2021 and rose to $1.3 trillion in 2022, according to Reason Foundation. The funded ratio of state pensions was just 85 percent in 2021 and has fallen below 75 percent in 2022.

What happened in the years of negative rates and massive currency printing? Pension funds used liability-driven investing (LDI) strategies. Most LDI mandates used derivatives to hedge inflation and interest rate risk. And what happens when inflation kicks in and rates rise?

“As interest rates have risen, the notional value of some of the derivatives held in LDI portfolios has fallen. The result: increased collateral calls. The speed at which rates have risen means some pension plans have had to liquidate portfolios to meet collateral calls, according to the Investment Association’s latest report in September,” writes Brian Croce and colleagues at Pensions & Investment.

The total assets in LDI strategies have almost quadrupled to 1.6 trillion pounds ($1.8 trillion) in the 10 years through 2021. “Nearly two-thirds of Britain’s defined benefit pension schemes use LDI funds, according to [The Pensions Regulator],” Reuters reported.

Truss and her former Chancellor of the Exchequer Kwasi Kwarteng aren’t to blame for this insanity. The policy of negative real rates and massive liquidity injection by the Bank of England is. Kwarteng and Truss are only to blame for believing that the policies of spending and printing defended by almost all mainstream Keynesian economists should work even when the music stops.

In these past years, British and developed nations’ governments didn’t pay any attention to fiscal imbalances because money was cheap and abundant. Deficits soared, spending was uncontrolled, and the problem was hidden in the balance sheet of central banks that, like the Bank of England, purchased more than 100 percent of net issuances of government debt. After years of printing money and increasing debt to new all-time highs, persistent high inflation appeared, and now central banks need to hike rates and reduce money supply growth just when fixed-income funds are loaded with toxic debt at negative nominal and real yields. And the rate hikes mean margin calls are more expensive and losses are unbearable.

UK pension funds need to get rid of the liquid assets they own as margin calls rise. Inflation arrived after years of massive currency printing and debt monetization, and investment funds all over the world—but especially in the euro area, UK, and Japan—are seeing their portfolios melt down with massive nominal and real losses. When margin calls kick in, many need to sell their most liquid assets, Gilts in the UK, or government bonds elsewhere.

Truss and Kwarteng aren’t to blame for the insanity of the past years or the previous chancellor Rishi Sunak’s ultra-Keynesian budgets. They’re only to blame for believing that another dose of Keynesian deficit insanity would not do any harm.

Kwarteng’s demise is just a casualty delivered by the modern monetary theory crowd and the monetary laughing gas city to justify that the problem was a ludicrous tax cut and not years of currency printing and deficit increases.

What has happened in the UK or Japan is likely to happen soon in the eurozone, which accumulated more than 12 billion euros of negative-yielding bonds in the years of cheap money and reckless stimulus plans.

Truss isn’t to blame for 20 years of monetary insanity and fiscal irresponsibility. She’s to blame for a budget that increases spending without cutting unnecessary expenses.

The irony of it all is that the defenders of monster deficits and borrowing if it comes from bloating the size of government feel vindicated. It was the evil tax cuts!

The political analysis of the mini-budget is astonishing. No one in the UK parliament sees any need to cut spending it seems, yet those expenses are consolidated and annualized, which means that any change in the economic cycle leads to larger fiscal imbalances as receipts are cyclical and, with it, more currency printing. The assumption that raising taxes will generate perennial annual increases in receipts no matter what happens to the economic cycle can only be defended by a bureaucrat.

Deficits are always a spending problem. Bloomberg Economics’ analysis shows that if a U-turn in tax cuts had no impact on economic growth, if it generated the receipts they estimate and borrowing costs ease—three enormous and impossible “ifs”—the financial hole in the UK budget would still be 24 billion pounds only to keep the debt to GDP ratio stable.

Every time a UK government buys the argument that higher tax rates finance higher annual and consolidated spending, they get one step away from being a leading global economy and closer to bringing the UK back to the 1970s.

Even assuming no impact on the economy, “keeping the planned rise in corporation tax to 25% from 19% from April 2023, which [Jeremy] Hunt’s predecessor Kwasi Kwarteng intended to cancel in the mini-budget, saves about £19 billion,” writes Jamie Rush at Bloomberg. However, that saving figure may be optimistic as it considers a level of earnings and profits in the United Kingdom that are more than debatable as we see consensus corporate earnings estimates fall month after month.

Jeremy Hunt, the new chancellor of the exchequer, seems to believe that raising taxes and massively increasing spending will calm markets. Why? Following the Japan and eurozone model of fiscal consolidation via receipts doesn’t work. More taxes and more spending mean less growth, less employment, weaker real wages, and more debt. Furthermore, it isn’t calming markets in those nations either, because the turmoil is coming from the hangover of cheap money excess, not a modest tax cut. More importantly, increasing the tax wedge and spending burden perennially damages the UK’s possibilities of becoming a country that attracts investment and capital from the rest of the world.

Truss should have presented the budget she believes in, not the one that she thought that consensus would buy. By presenting an “expansionary” spending budget that she probably didn’t even believe in sprinkled with a few modest tax cuts she handed her opponents the axe to use against her, and the opportunity to attack came from a global market collapse and blaming it all on minuscule tax incentives.

Meanwhile, Labour in the UK demands more monetary and fiscal insanity with an economic program that aims to increase spending even more and finance the deficits with monetization of debt. And some call that “calming the market.”

The only lesson for the United Kingdom is to remember that if you follow Greece’s economic policies, you get Greek debt, unemployment, and growth. The UK government should do everything to avoid the seventies’ elevated inflation and economic stagnation, not try to vigorously replicate them.

Views expressed in this article are the opinions of the author and do not necessarily reflect the views of The Epoch Times.


Follow

Daniel Lacalle, Ph.D., is chief economist at hedge fund Tressis and author of “Freedom or Equality,” “Escape from the Central Bank Trap,” and “Life in the Financial Markets.”